Pages

Monday, December 1, 2008

2008-12-01 - Work in Progress - Unfinished

 

From Minsky Moment to Minsky Meltdown to…?

Learning to Stop Underestimating the Likelihood of

“High Impact, Low Probability” Events

 

Liquidity Trap and Depression is a Serious Risk

 

Warning - Unfinished - Work in Progress 


It isn’t called the dismal science for nothing!

The evolution of capital markets prices will be determined largely by (a) the evolution of what will come for the economy and (b) how much of that has already been reflected in asset prices. Such a statement of the seemingly obvious would normally be implicit and left unsaid, but its explicit statement seems warranted by the combination of the extraordinary nature of the times, the degree of uncertainty on the outlook, and the volatility of the markets (perhaps suggestive of the tenuousness of market participants’ convictions, in particular due to the unpredictability to date of government policy interventions).

Clearly, asset prices (credit spreads, equity values and commodity prices, in particular) went from, in September and earlier, pricing in expectations of a moderately bad economic environment to, in October and November, pricing in expectations of a rather worse -- and more intransigent -- economic outcome.

But how bad an economic outcome exactly is likely, and did the markets, at their worst, finally go too far? (And, hence, the bounce from those levels is warranted.) Or is the process that we’ve witnessed this year of the markets continuously playing catch-up to the economic reality (as it evolves, incorporating the various feedback loop effects) ongoing? (And, as such, the worst has not yet been priced in and there are further lows to come.)

Equity and commodity markets, in particular, were relatively slow to discard their optimistic assumptions, including, for instance, that subprime is contained, that housing was bottoming, that there would be global decoupling, that the U.S. consumer is resilient, that the corporate sector has strong balance sheets, that (each successive round of) extraordinary government policy intervention would cure our ills, that emerging markets were exempt from the developed world’s problems, etc.

But does a breach of 800 on the S&P and of $50 on oil suggest that we’ve finally reached capitulation? Or has the severity of the situation still not been fully assessed, implying that as far as markets have retreated, many prices have still not reverted far enough to reach fair values based on a realistic assessment of our ultimate outcome? Or, alternatively, is it perhaps then possible that the process of discarding optimism may be done, and market prices did in fact reach reasonable approximations of fair value, but there remains plenty of room to become even more pessimistic? (Markets, after all, are notorious for overshooting.)

The answers to these questions rely largely on the answer to the following one:

How bad a recession?

As Harry Truman said, a recession is when your neighbour loses his job, a depression is when you lose yours.

The NBER has (finally) acknowledged that the U.S. economy is, and has been for some time, in a recession. This did not require that the U.S. economy post two consecutive quarters of negative GDP growth (the popular rule of thumb). The Business Cycle Dating Committee at the National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) maintains a chronology of the U.S. business cycle: “The chronology identifies the dates of peaks and troughs that frame economic recession or expansion. The period from a peak to a trough is a recession and the period from a trough to a peak is an expansion… A recession is a significant decline in economic activity spread across the economy, lasting more than a few months, normally visible in real GDP, real income, employment, industrial production, and wholesale-retail sales. A recession begins just after the economy reaches a peak of activity and ends as the economy reaches its trough.” The Committee does not apply a fixed rule for how the different indicators that they evaluate are weighted, and they may declare a peak (or trough) in the business cycle anywhere from 6 to 18 months after the fact, with the intention of waiting long enough so that the existence (and timing) of a recession is not at all in doubt. In this case, they waited until December 2008 to identify that December 2007 was the peak of the last business cycle. This current recession, then, is already 12 months long, which is longer than the average post-WWII recession. (At least some of the “experts” on CNBC deemed this a good sign, as it could therefore be taken to imply that the recession must be nearing its end. If only it were true!)

In 2007, it was considered questionable whether the U.S. economy would suffer a recession at all, and, even if so, the consensus was that other global economies would survive relatively unscathed. The notion that the U.S. economy could be at risk of entering a depression was then viewed as outlandish. However, times have changed, and comparisons to 1990s Japan and even the 1930s Great Depression have since become almost commonplace.

Before the Great Depression of the 1930s any downturn in economic activity was referred to as a depression. The term recession was then developed to differentiate periods like the 1930s from smaller economic declines, such as those that occurred in 1910 and 1913. There is, however, no standard definition of what constitutes a depression; the NBER does not declare or define economic depressions. However, it does say that “the term depression is often used to refer to a particularly severe period of economic weakness. Some economists use it to refer only to the portion of these periods when economic activity is declining. The more common use, however, also encompasses the time until economic activity has returned to close to normal levels.”

Though the odds of revisiting the depths of the Great Depression are low, thanks in large part to the lessons learned from that episode (and the macroeconomic policies and countercyclical programs that were the result of those lessons), that is not to say that the probability of A depression is equally low. If a depression is, as most would agree, a prolonged period of recession, or a significant and prolonged downturn in the economy, characterized by declining business activities, falling prices, rising unemployment, increasing inventories (and a degree of public fear), there is certainly some degree of likelihood that such an outcome could result. In fact, it is the purpose of this paper to document that such a risk is indeed quite significant.

The Great One

Marriner S. Eccles served as Franklin D. Roosevelt's Chairman of the Federal Reserve from November 1934 to February 1948. He detailed in his memoirs what he believed caused the Great Depression:

As mass production has to be accompanied by mass consumption, mass consumption, in turn, implies a distribution of wealth -- not of existing wealth, but of wealth as it is currently produced -- to provide men with buying power equal to the amount of goods and services offered by the nation's economic machinery.

Instead of achieving that kind of distribution, a giant suction pump had by 1929-30 drawn into a few hands an increasing portion of currently produced wealth. This served them as capital accumulations. But by taking purchasing power out of the hands of mass consumers, the savers denied to themselves the kind of effective demand for their products that would justify a reinvestment of their capital accumulations in new plants. In consequence, as in a poker game where the chips were concentrated in fewer and fewer hands, the other fellows could stay in the game only by borrowing. When their credit ran out, the game stopped.

That is what happened to us in the twenties. We sustained high levels of employment in that period with the aid of an exceptional expansion of debt outside of the banking system. This debt was provided by the large growth of business savings as well as savings by individuals, particularly in the upper-income groups where taxes were relatively low. Private debt outside of the banking system increased about fifty per cent. This debt, which was at high interest rates, largely took the form of mortgage debt on housing, office, and hotel structures, consumer installment debt, brokers' loans, and foreign debt. The stimulation to spend by debt-creation of this sort was short-lived and could not be counted on to sustain high levels of employment for long periods of time. Had there been a better distribution of the current income from the national product -- in other words, had there been less savings by business and the higher-income groups and more income in the lower groups -- we should have had far greater stability in our economy. Had the six billion dollars, for instance, that were loaned by corporations and wealthy individuals for stock-market speculation been distributed to the public as lower prices or higher wages and with less profits to the corporations and the well-to-do, it would have prevented or greatly moderated the economic collapse that began at the end of 1929.

The time came when there were no more poker chips to be loaned on credit. Debtors thereupon were forced to curtail their consumption in an effort to create a margin that could be applied to the reduction of outstanding debts. This naturally reduced the demand for goods of all kinds and brought on what seemed to be overproduction, but was in reality underconsumption when judged in terms of the real world instead of the money world. This, in turn, brought about a fall in prices and employment.

Unemployment further decreased the consumption of goods, which further increased unemployment, thus closing the circle in a continuing decline of prices. Earnings began to disappear, requiring economies of all kinds in the wages, salaries, and time of those employed. And thus again the vicious circle of deflation was closed until one third of the entire working population was unemployed, with our national income reduced by fifty per cent, and with the aggregate debt burden greater than ever before, not in dollars, but measured by current values and income that represented the ability to pay. Fixed charges, such as taxes, railroad and other utility rates, insurance and interest charges, clung close to the 1929 level and required such a portion of the national income to meet them that the amount left for consumption of goods was not sufficient to support the population.

This then, was my reading of what brought on the depression.

Based on this account, it seems clear that there are a number of parallels between the situation that prevailed in the lead-up to the Great Depression and that which has pertained recently: inequitable income distribution, excessive credit growth and leverage, misallocation of resources and malinvestment, excess consumption.

 

Lesson learned: “You're right, we did it. We're very sorry. But thanks to you, we won't do it again.”

On the occasion of Milton Friedman’s 90th birthday, at a conference at the University of Chicago in November 2002, Ben Bernanke, then a Governor of the Federal Reserve, said: “Let me end my talk by abusing slightly my status as an official representative of the Federal Reserve. I would like to say to Milton and Anna: Regarding the Great Depression. You're right, we did it. We're very sorry. But thanks to you, we won't do it again.”

Bernanke was saluting Friedman and Schwartz because they, in Bernanke’s words, “provided what has become the leading and most persuasive explanation of the worst economic disaster in American history”, in their 1963 tome, A Monetary History of the United States. Their view was that the economic collapse was the product of monetary forces, and that the Fed was to blame for allowing the money supply to contract by one-third, turning a garden-variety recession into the disaster it became. This was quite controversial at the time, but the monetarist perspective gained much more credibility during the inflationary episode of the 1970s, and, by 1976, Friedman had won the Nobel Prize.

Bernanke, who has spent a good portion of his professional life studying the Great Depression, and is widely-acknowledged as one of the foremost experts on it, obviously seems intent on ensuring he honours the oath he made to Milton and Anna. The variety of liquidity facilities the Fed has put on offer, to an ever-expanding range of companies (not just depository institutions), and against increasingly suspect collateral, along with the dramatic expansion of the Fed’s balance sheet in recent weeks, is testament to his determination. In fact, the Fed’s maneuverings run contrary to a principle once held dear by many central bankers, Walter Bagehot’s famous 1873 dictum that a lender of last resort in a crisis should lend freely, but at a penalty rate, to solvent but illiquid banks that have adequate collateral.

The problem is, as so succinctly described by Mark Twain, that “to a man with a hammer, everything looks like a nail”. Bernanke’s “hammer” is his understanding of the causes and consequences of the Great Depression, and the alternative policy prescriptions he has determined should have been implemented at the time. His “nail” is this unfortunate current circumstance, which provides the (fortuitous?) opportunity to put his years of research into practice (it must have been fate that one of the world’s foremost experts on the Great Depression was in place to address Round Two!).

None other than Ms. Schwartz, who Bernanke effusively praised for her analysis with Friedman of the Great Depression, believes Bernanke and the Fed are fighting the last war. "The Fed has gone about as if the problem is a shortage of liquidity. That is not the basic problem”, she argues. “The basic problem for the markets is that [uncertainty] that the balance sheets of financial firms are credible." In the 1930s, the country and the Federal Reserve were faced with a liquidity crisis in the banking sector. As weak banks failed, depositors worried that their bank would be next, which prompted bank runs on otherwise healthy institutions. At the time, that Fed also did not heed Bagehot’s advice, but in that case it was by sitting idly by, so bank after bank failed, causing a self-reinforcing spiral, bringing down principally banks that should not have been in distress. But "that's not what's going on in the market now," Ms. Schwartz says. “Today, the banks have a problem on the asset side of their ledgers -- all these exotic securities that the market does not know how to value…Why are they 'toxic'?" Ms. Schwartz asks. "They're toxic because you cannot sell them, you don't know what they're worth, your balance sheet is not credible and the whole market freezes up. We don't know whom to lend to because we don't know who is sound. So if you could get rid of them, that would be an improvement."

As such, Ms. Schwartz actually believed that the first incarnation of the TARP was a step in the right direction, though with a potentially intractable problem: the question of how to price the assets the TARP would acquire. If priced at current market values, the assets’ sale would instantly make many institutions insolvent, which would of course instantly realize the fears that were and are currently locking up the credit markets, as a number of banks failed. This realization is surely why TARP v.1 became TARP v.2, with Paulson changing gears to recapitalize firms directly. Ms. Schwartz believes this change in plan was tantamount to changing the objective from trying to save the banking system to instead trying to save the banks. But by keeping otherwise insolvent banks alive, the government is prolonging the crisis. Rather, "firms that made wrong decisions should fail," she says bluntly. "You shouldn't rescue them. And once that's established as a principle, I think the market recognizes that it makes sense. Everything works much better when wrong decisions are punished and good decisions make you rich."

Predicting the Improbable

Roger M. Kubarych is Chief US Economist of UniCredit Global Research, and is also the Henry Kaufman Adjunct Senior Fellow for International Economics and Finance at the Council on Foreign Relations. It is his view that “nobody likes to pay attention to low probability, high-cost events. We've see this over and over again. And so you bring up to somebody in authority that if this happens and this happens, then this will be the result. It isn't that you are dismissed as being adolescent or puerile, you're just too early. There's a great story that Chuck Brunie has written about Milton Friedman, for whom he managed money. And Brunie talks of once asking Milton that as one of the most distinguished economists in the world why he needed someone like Chuck to manage his money. And Friedman replied, "Chuck, I see things too early."”

It is to be hoped that the advances in economic policies, research, and, more simply, understanding should leave policymakers today better suited to accurately assessing the likely course for the economy. Recent events, however, cast doubt on that view.

At the Cato Institute’s 26th Annual Monetary Conference in November, 2008, Don Kohn provided the keynote address, in which he explained why, despite the lessons learned from recent experience, he, like many other members of the FOMC, still believes that monetary policy should not be used to influence asset prices. One of his key arguments was that identification of an asset bubble in real-time is very tricky. He now recognizes that the Fed underestimated the scope for housing prices to fall and therefore also underestimated the severe economic fallout and thus the difficulty of mopping up afterwards. After his speech, in the Q&A session, when asked to address the risks of a Japanese-style deflation in the U.S., Mr. Kohn explained his view that the probability of such a scenario unfolding now has increased over recent months, but nonetheless remains very low. However, he did insist that if the Fed did come to believe such a scenario likely, it would act very quickly and very aggressively to prevent it.

Thus, on the one hand, Mr. Kohn insisted the Fed could not identify asset bubbles (even extraordinarily obvious ones like housing, by virtue of fairly basic metrics like price-to-rent and price-to-income ratios). He also effectively admitted the Fed was lacking the insight or imagination to foresee, despite the fact that housing was a clear leading indicator in 8 of the last 10 U.S. recessions, that the unwinding of the housing bubble would have severe consequences. Meanwhile, on the other hand, he attempted to reassure that the Fed would be very proactive, as would be required, to prevent a deflationary spiral if one were to become a risk.

This is hardly reassuring talk from a policymaking institution that has so obviously failed to appreciate the gravity of the situation it found itself conducting policy in. For instance, Ben Bernanke famously declared repeatedly throughout the spring of 2007 that the problems in subprime were likely to remain contained, a mistake he just recently acknowledged. As a second example, the Fed effectively ignored the recommendations of one of its own Governors, Fredric Mishkin, who, at the Jackson Hole Conference in August 2007, urged central bankers to respond quickly and aggressively to large falls in housing prices with immediate large scale interest rate cuts. Mishkin argued, to no avail, that a delay in a policy approach would just guarantee that when easier policy was finally implemented it would be much less effective and therefore need to be of even greater magnitude. This was hardly the only occasion of an FOMC member’s good advice being ignored, as Alan Greenspan continuously rebuffed warnings about the risk due to increasingly unscrupulous behaviour in subprime mortgages, including from former Governor Ed Gramlich. Greenspan has belatedly offered his own unique version of a mea culpa, admitting in testimony in October before the House Committee of Government Oversight that he was wrong about regulation: "I made a mistake in presuming that the self-interests of organizations, specifically banks and others, were such as that they were best capable of protecting their own shareholders and their equity in the firms," and said his free-market ideology was flawed-- "I don’t know how significant or permanent it is. But I have been very distressed by that fact... I was shocked, because I have been going for 40 years or more with very considerable evidence that it was working exceptionally well.”

 

As Dean Baker, one of the economists who predicted the current predicament, put it in October 2007, “It is disconcerting to hear that the weakness in the housing market is greater "than had previously been expected" will be "more prolonged than had seemed likely" or would persist longer "than previously anticipated." The members of the Federal Reserve Board are supposed to be knowledgeable about the economy and therefore should not be continually surprised by events. The fact that they have been repeatedly surprised by the weakness in the housing market raises serious questions about their competence.” Based on the above, it does not seem credible to believe that government policymakers necessarily have the requisite knowledge, insight and tools to sufficiently address the problems it faces.

 

Are We Japan (Bad) or Are We Sweden (Good)

It is always easier to give advice to others than to put it into action yourself. Many American economists were quite critical of Japanese policymakers in the 1990s.

Hypocritical? U.S. has been faster and more aggressive on some fronts (int rt cuts; albeit not as fast as Mishkin and others would have like; missed opportunities in 2007 due to failure of vision) but failing to follow the advice it gave Japan on other fronts (take your pain up front; let/force the weak to die while supporting the strong; use FDIC and bankruptcy for what they were designed for (WAMU example may have been worse than LEH in terms of f’g up prospects of financials raising more capital in the private markets)

As Yves Smith, who authors the blog naked capitalism, is fond of saying, “persisting in a failed course of action is not a sign of intelligence.” None of the liquidity facilities enacted by the Fed to date has proven effective at stemming the credit crunch, yet the Fed insists on repeatedly returning to that same old dry well. This goes back to Anna Schwartz’s observation – the fact of the matter is that the Fed’s programs are designed to address a liquidity crisis, but this is not a liquidity crisis, it is a credit crisis (or debt crisis, or solvency crisis).

….

Fed transparency a thing of the past --- disingenuous about quant easing; refusing to disclose the banks it has lent to or the assets it has bought (Willem Buiter calls this a symptom of the Fed’s cognitive regulatory capture; this is a type of concession (in order to avoid stigma?) the banks have not earned, and has not been granted to anyone else, including automakers, who have had to hang their dirty laundry in public, as they should if they’re begging for public funds

….

 

 

Great Depression Round Two – What’s the Right Parallel?

Earlier in this paper, I have alluded to the similarities between the U.S. today and the U.S. in 1930. While those similarities remain germane, to the extent that the imbalances in the U.S. economy over the last decade have left it susceptible to terrible reversals, the more relevant --- and disturbing --- comparison is between China today and the U.S. of 1930.

 

It is China today that plays the part that 1930 U.S. did, while the U.S. today is more akin to 1930 U.K.

 

U.S. then / China now --- world’s largest creditor and exporter

 

1930s Smoot-Hawley --- today, beggar-thy-neighbour exchange rate depreciation, export subsidies; plus collapse of shipping; BDI down 94%, Cass Freight similar; letter of credit for trade n/a; ports (Long Beach, L.A.) => activity slowing, plus what is being offloaded is sitting warehoused not going anywhere

 

…..

China showing signs of slowing dramatically

Exports and investment primary sources of growth; personal spending was growing at a fast rate, but (a) still a very low proportion of economy, (b) very cyclical, and very reliant on income growth (personal savings huge in China b/c no social safety net (nor even a large stable of kids to support you); (c) food a larger component of spending, and growth in spending was in large part a food price effect; (d) factories shutting down like crazy, workers losing their jobs (riots already); investment was for exports, so as X slows, so too does investment;

Fiscal stimulus may have had less to it than meets the eye

 

 

Contemporary forecasts of doom and gloom

You no longer have to resort to reading the bearish analysis of prescient economist Nouriel Roubini to receive a significant dose of doom and gloom. In fact, you don’t have to read economists at all, not when chief executives provide assessments such as these:

JP Morgan Chase & Co. CEO Jamie Dimon, November 11, 2008

“We think the economy could be worse than the capital-markets crisis. You really need to separate them because they have completely different effects on our businesses and on most businesses.''

 

Merrill Lynch Chairman and CEO John Thain, November 11, 2008

“Right now, the US economy is contracting very rapidly. We are looking at a per­iod of global slowdown. This is not like 1987 or 1998 or 2001. The contraction going on is bigger than that. We will in fact look back to the 1929 period to see the kind of slow­down we’re seeing now.”

 

Former Goldman Sachs Chairman John Whitehead, November 11, 2008

“I think it would be worse than the depression. We’re talking about reducing the credit of the United States of America, which is the backbone of the economic system…. I see nothing but large increases in the deficit, all of which are serving to decrease the credit standing of America. … I just want to get people thinking about this and to realize this is a road to disaster. I’ve always been a positive person and optimistic, but I don’t see a solution here.”

 

Oppenheimer & Co. Managing Director Meredith Whitney, Nov. 30, 2008

“My outlook has been negative for over a year and, technically, I have been “right” on my calls. Seeing massive capital destruction has brought me no pleasure, but unfortunately I see little on the horizon that would change my outlook. In fact, after observing the US economy so derailed, I feel that I must act as a citizen of this great country to attempt to offer solutions to this economic train wreck we are all involved in. First, I am more bearish today than I have been in the past 18 months.”

 

 

analysis of the global outlook from JPMorgan Chase, once among the most bullish of analysts, in 2007-08 leading voice arguing about risks of global inflation. Now, under the rubric “A bad week in hell”, JPMorgan states that: “Increasingly signs point to a deep and synchronized global recession” ; “Once again, we have taken an axe to near-term growth forecasts for the developed world and will likely follow up with additional downward revisions for emerging economies in the coming weeks. Already, our forecasts suggest that global gross domestic product will contract at a near 1 per cent annual rate” in the fourth quarter of 2008 and the first quarter of 2009” ; “it is likely that the coming six months will see headline inflation dip below zero” ;

JPMorgan expects shrinkage this quarter at an annualised rate of 4 per cent in the US, 3 per cent in the UK and 2 per cent in the eurozone. It is forecasting 0.4 per cent global growth in 2009, with advanced countries shrinking 0.5 per cent and emerging ones growing 4.2 per cent.

 

Minsky, Money and Liquidity Traps

 

Financial instability hypothesis; Ponzi finance, etc.

 

…..

 

Keynes

“Speculators may do no harm as bubbles on a steady stream of enterprise. But the position is serious when enterprise becomes the bubble on a whirlpool of speculation. When the capital development of a country becomes a by-product of the activities of a casino, the job is likely to be ill-done.”

 

….

 

Quantitative easing – how it works and its limitations

 

….

 

MV = PQ

Velocity falling

Fed pumping up monetary base, but being hoarded, so broader measures of M no change

 

 

Debt, Debt and More Debt

 

No end to this until debt has become supportable ---- a prospect which continues to be pushed into the future by virtue of declining employment and incomes, declining wealth via housing and equity market sell-offs, while aggregate debt continues to increase

 

 

 

Global Imbalances

 

(A) Deflation and lqdty trap à bond rally has room to run

Supply (govt supply) is coming, but its merely offsetting dropoff in bond issuance in private sector (securitized and otherwise), plus bond demand should be expected to rise (private sector balance sheets have bonds at historically low level as proportion of assets; pension funds also have room to add (more LDI when alternative long-duration assets (stocks) not working out too well)

….

But (B) what if global imbalances start to unwind (and quickly)?

That which is unsustainable by definition won’t be sustained

….

Cyclical vs secular --- (A) has been trumping (B) recently and seems likely to continue to do so in short term but not in long term; ? is, when can we expect the tipping point?

Frankly, nobody freaking knows --- no facts to make a good estimation of this on ---- speculation abounds

 


REFERENCES

Bernanke, Ben. “On Milton Friedman's Ninetieth Birthday; Remarks by Governor Ben S. Bernanke at the Conference to Honor Milton Friedman, University of Chicago, Chicago, Illinois; November 8, 2002

Backstrom, Urban. “What Lessons Can Be Learned From Recent Financial Crises? The Swedish Experience”

King, Stephen. “How to Cope With Depression.” HSBC Economics. September 23, 2008.

Krugman, Paul. “Japan’s Trap”. May 1998

Krugman, Paul. “Thinking About the Liquidity Trap”. December 1999

Kuttner, Robert. “The Alarming Parallels Between 1929 and 2007: Testimony of Robert Kuttner Before the Committee on Financial Services”. The American Prospect. October 2, 2007.

Leamer, Edward. “Housing IS the Business Cycle.” NBER. September 2007.

Reinhart, Carmen and Kenneth Rogoff. “Is the 2007 U.S. Sub-Prime Financial Crisis So Different? An International Historical Comparison”. February 2008.

Reinhart, Carmen and Kenneth Rogoff. “This Time is Different: A Panoramic View of Eight Centuries of Financial Crises”. April, 2008.

Schwartz, Anna. “Bernanke Is Fighting the Last War”. Wall Street Journal. October 18, 2008.

Tymoigne, Eric. “Minsky and Economic Policy: “Keynesianism” All Over Again?”. October 2008.

Whalen, Charles. “The U.S. Credit Crunch of 2007: A Minsky Moment”. October 2007.

Wray, L. Randall. “Financial Markets Meltdown: What Can We Learn From Minsky?”. 2008.

 

 

Other Analysts, Economists and Investors Worth Listening To:

Economists

(from more alarmist to more conventional)

Analysts and Investors

Nouriel Roubini

Satyajit Das

Robert Shiller

Meredith Whitney

Paul Krugman

Albert Edwards and James Montier

Kenneth Rogoff and Carment Reinhart

Nassim Nicholas Taleb

Joseph Stiglitz

James Grant

Stephen Roach

Jeremy Grantham

David Rosenberg and David Wolf

 

Jan Hatzius

 



APPENDIX

 

2008Q3 Forecast Notes (need to include charts to address these points)

None of us has the time here today to fully address all the facts and assumptions that motivate our forecasts and to do those topics any justice, so I’m going to be selective today about what I discuss and focus on.

First, I’ll just briefly review some key forces at play, before digging a bit deeper into one particular topic.

-        In 2006, I focused a lot on how the housing bubble was morphing into the most serious housing recession in the post-WWII period, and how housing has historically been a leading indicator of turning points in the economic cycle, which did not portend well for an economic soft landing.

o    All I can add on this topic is that bottom-callers these days are just as likely to be wrong now as they were in late 2006 and all through 2007

o    Obviously we are now closer to the bottom than we were then, but that does not mean it’s imminent

o    Housing prices remain well above historical norms with respect to either incomes or rents, the overbuilding of the last decade has in no way been worked off, so inventories remain high, foreclosures and delinquency rates continue to climb, and though mortgage rates have come down, affordability has not because of the tightening of credit conditions

 

-        Many times in 2007, I detailed the deterioration in the U.S. labour market, highlighting both the faultiness of the NFP data due to the Birth/Death model, and that year-over-year employment growth slowing as much as it had was historically a very accurate indicator of recession

o    Obviously, the news on this front has gotten no better since then, with 8 straight months of job losses, the main unemployment rate 1.7% higher than its cycle low, at 6.1%, and the most comprehensive measure of unemployment up 2.8% from its cycle low, to 10.7%, the highest since 1994

 

-        Around this time last year, I highlighted a number of leading indicators, in addition the to housing and labour market data, that had also served as useful leading recessionary indicators, including Paul Kasriel’s combination of a yield curve inversion along with a YoY drop in the CPI-adjusted monetary base, the coincident-lagging index, etc.

o    A quick update on this front is that the Chicago Fed NAI was just released for August and its value marked the ninth consecutive month that it indicated a strong likelihood that a recession had begun

 

-        In spring 2007, I focused on the economy’s unsustainable debt growth, and that I believed a Minsky moment would ultimately occur, whereby the credit markets reached a tipping point, unleashing a vicious circle of necessary deleveraging.

o    Clearly, this is ongoing, and the only comments I’d like to add is that the probabilities of either a Japanese-like deflationary lost decade or the most serious recession since the Great Depression are materially higher now than they were when I first forecast their risk

o    What’s more, at the aggregate level, there really hasn’t been much, if any, real deleveraging yet

§   Financial institutions have not raised sufficient new capital to offset the writedowns they’ve taken, so their leverage hasn’t in aggregate been reduced

§   Despite tighter lending conditions, household debt has continued to grow, so income is down and wealth has been down for three quarters in a row, but debt has actually built further

§   So debt burdens all around have become nothing if not more onerous

 

-        I’ve also discussed in the past that the theory about global decoupling would eventually be proven a fallacy

o    On this front, it has become clear that the OECD, particularly Europe and Japan, has recoupled, as the previous period of supposed resilience has been shown just to be a matter of lags

o    Though the outcome for emerging markets is not yet apparent, I’ll stick to my view that they will suffer the same fate, though to a lesser degree, though just to a more lagged extent

 

-        The main topic I’d like to address today, though, is the latest incarnation of government intervention, the Toxic Asset Relief Program, or TARP, which is doomed to failure

o    It will be no more effective than any of the previous cases of government meddling, from the Hank’s MLEC Super SIV and HOPENow to Ben’s liquidity measures and rate cuts to the Bear takeunder, to the inconsistent approaches taken to the GSEs vs AIG vs. LEH vs. Wachovia and WAMU, etc.

§   The TARP simply reshuffles the deck chairs on the Titanic; it doesn’t do anything to solve the problem of bad assets (leveraged-up exposure to less-than-creditworthy borrowers), its just a proposal for the taxpayer to take on the burden of the private sectors greed-fueled mistakes

§   Either the TARP buys assets at true market value, which locks in losses for the company selling the assets and meanwhile also establishes a real market price to which other institutions must mark their similar exposures down to, forcing their insolvency; or it pays substantially inflated values, which exposes taxpayers to the credit risk, and inculcates a policy of privatized profits / socialized losses, while not solving the problem as foreclosures and defaults continue rising

§   The only approach that has a chance of working is a taxpayer-to-taxpayer relief program that addresses income inequality to stem tide of defaults

 

No comments: